IB87020: Campaign Financing

January 23, 2001

Joseph E. Cantor
Government and Finance Division


CONTENTS


SUMMARY

Concerns over financing federal elections have become a seemingly perennial aspect of our political system, centered on the enduring issues of high campaign costs and reliance on interest groups for needed campaign funds.

Rising election costs have long fostered a sense in some quarters that spending is out of control, with too much time spent raising funds and elections "bought and sold." Debate has also focused on the role of interest groups in campaign funding, especially through political action committees (PACs).

The differences in perceptions of the campaign finance system have long been compounded by different reform approaches of the major parties. Democrats have tended to favor more regulation, with spending limits and some form of public funding or benefits a part of their past proposals. Republicans have generally opposed such limits and public funding.

The Democratic majority in the 101st-103rd Congresses passed bills with spending limits, benefits, and PAC and loophole curbs. The 101st and 103rd Congress bills were not reconciled; a 102nd Congress conference bill was vetoed. Reformers in the 104th Congress sought a similar measure but failed on a Senate cloture vote; House Republicans offered a bill giving parties and local citizens a greater role, which was defeated, as was a Democratic alternative.

The 1996 elections marked a turning point, when the focus of the debate shifted from further restrictions on already-regulated spending and funding sources to activities largely or entirely outside federal election law regulation and disclosure requirements. Although concerns had long been rising over soft money in federal elections, the widespread and growing use of soft money for so-called issue advocacy since 1996 has raised questions over the integrity of current regulations and the feasibility of any limits on campaign money.

In the 105th Congress, the first Congress after 1996, the House debated reform twice. First, it considered a GOP-leadership bill and three narrower measures under suspension of rules, passing a foreign national contribution ban and an FEC disclosure/enforcement bill and defeating the leadership bill and the Paycheck Protection Act. In response to a discharge petition drive, the House renewed consideration of the issue, in a lengthy process focused on the "freshman bipartisan bill," 11 substitutes, and a constitutional amendment. Debate ended with passage of the Shays-Meehan bill. The Senate debated the companion McCain-Feingold bill three times, all ending in failed cloture votes.

In the first session of the 106th Congress, the House passed the Shays-Meehan bill, but Senate debate ended after two failed cloture votes. In the second session, Congress did agree on an aspect of campaign reform, in passing P.L. 106-230, to require disclosure by certain tax-exempt political organizations organized under section 527 of the Internal Revenue Code. Such groups exist to influence elections, but many had not been required to disclose to the Federal Election Commission.

Reform supporters in the 107th Congress have vowed to pick up where they left off in the last Congress. Senate supporters are pushing for debate on the McCain-Feingold bill early in the first session.


MOST RECENT DEVELOPMENTS

The closer party split in both houses of Congress since the 2000 elections has given reformers renewed hope of passing legislation in the 107th Congress. On January 22, the 107th Congress version of the McCain-Feingold bill was introduced-S. 27, and supporters are seeking a debate and vote early in the first session.


BACKGROUND AND ANALYSIS

Evolution of the Current System

Today's federal campaign finance law evolved during the 1970s out of five major statutes and a paramount Supreme Court case. That case not only affected earlier statutes, but it continues to shape the dialogue on campaign finance reform.

The 1971 Federal Election Campaign Act (FECA), as amended in 1974, 1976, and 1979, imposed limits on contributions, required disclosure of campaign receipts and expenditures, and set up the Federal Election Commission (FEC) as a central administrative and enforcement agency. The Revenue Act of 1971 inaugurated public funding of presidential general elections, with funding of primaries and nominating conventions added by the 1974 FECA Amendments. The latter also imposed certain expenditure limits, struck down by the Supreme Court's landmark Buckley v. Valeo ruling [424 U.S. 1 (1976)].

In the Buckley ruling, the Court upheld the Act's limitations on contributions as appropriate legislative tools to guard against the reality or appearance of improper influence stemming from candidates' dependence on large campaign contributions. However, Buckley invalidated the Act's limitations on independent expenditures, on candidate expenditures from personal funds, and on overall campaign expenditures. These provisions, the Court ruled, placed direct and substantial restrictions on the ability of candidates, citizens, and associations to engage in protected First Amendment rights. The Court saw no danger of corruption arising from large expenditures, as it did from large contributions, which alone could justify the First Amendment restrictions involved. Only voluntary limits could be sustained, perhaps in exchange for government benefits. Such a plan was specifically upheld in the existing presidential public funding system, as a contractual agreement between the government and the candidate. The Court's dichotomous ruling, allowing limits on contributions but striking down mandatory limits on expenditures, has shaped subsequent campaign finance practices and laws, as well as the debate over campaign finance reforms.

Campaign Finance Practices and Related Issues

Since the mid-1970s, the limits on contributions by individuals, political action committees (PACs), and parties, and an absence of congressional spending limits, have governed the flow of money in congressional elections. Throughout the 1980s and much of the 1990s, the two paramount issues raised by campaign finance practices were the phenomena of, first, rising campaign costs and the large amounts of money needed for elections and, second, the substantial reliance on PACs as a source of funding. Concerns were also voiced, by political scientists and the Republican congressional minority, over a third issue: the level of electoral competition, as affected by finance practices.

Since 1996, the debate has shifted considerably to a focus on the perceived loopholes in current law (a source of increasing debate since the mid-1980s). The PAC issue has been greatly supplanted by more fundamental issues of election regulation, with observers finding new appreciation for the limited, disclosed nature of PAC funds. Concerns over competition have abated since Republicans won control of Congress in 1994, despite the perceived incumbency bias in the finance system. The issue of high campaign costs and the concomitant need for vast resources continues to underlie the debate, but even this has been almost overshadowed by concerns over the system's perceived loopholes. Although these practices are (largely) presumably legal, they may violate the law's spirit, raising a basic question of whether money in elections can, let alone should, be regulated.

Longstanding Issues: Overall Costs, Funding Sources, and Competition

Increased Campaign Costs. Since first being systematically compiled in the 1970s, campaign expenditures have risen substantially, even exceeding the overall rise in the cost of living. Campaign finance authority Herbert Alexander estimated that $540 million was spent on all elections in the U.S. in 1976, rising to $4 billion in 1996. Aggregate costs of House and Senate campaigns more than sextupled between 1976 and 1996, from $115.5 million to $765.3 million, while the cost of living rose by less than threefold. Data for 1998 showed an overall decline to $740.4 million, with Senate spending nearly the same as in 1996 but House spending notably less than 1996, due, in some measure, to an almost 20% drop in the number of candidates. Campaign costs for average winning candidates, a useful measure of the real cost of seeking office, show an increase in the House from $87,000 in 1976 to $679,000 in 1996, with a drop to $666,000 in 1998; a winning Senate race went from $609,000 in 1976 to $3.8 million in 1996, increasing to $4.5 million in 1998. Complete data for 2000 are not yet available.

The above data are cited by many as evidence that our democratic system of government has suffered as election costs have grown to levels often considered exorbitant. Specifically, it is argued that officeholders must spend too much time raising money, at the expense of their public duties and communicating with constituents. The high cost of elections and the perception that they are "bought and sold" are seen as contributing to public cynicism about the political process. Some express concern that spiraling campaign costs has resulted in more wealthy individuals seeking office or determining election winners, denying opportunities for service to those lacking adequate resources or contacts. Others see a correlation between excessive, available money and the perceived increased reliance on sophisticated, often negative media advertising.

Not all observers view the high cost of elections with alarm. Many insist we do not spend too much on elections and maybe don't spend enough. They contrast the amount spent on elections with that spent by government at all levels, noting that only a fraction of a percent is spent to choose those who make vital decisions on the allocation of tax dollars. Similarly, they contrast costs of elections with those on commercial advertising: the nation's two leading commercial advertisers, Proctor & Gamble and General Motors, spent more to promote their products in 1996 ($5 billion) than was spent on all U.S. elections. In such a context, these observers contend, the costs of political dialogue may not be excessive.

High election costs are seen largely as a reflection of the paramount role of media in modern elections. Increasingly high television costs and costs of fundraising in an era of contribution limits require candidates to seek a broad base of small contributors--a democratic, but time-consuming, expensive process--or to seek ever-larger contributions from small groups of wealthy contributors. It has been argued that neither wealthy candidates nor negative campaigning are new or increasing phenomena but merely that better disclosure and television's prevalence make us more aware of them. Finally, better-funded candidates do not always win, as some recent elections show.

PACs and Other Sources of Campaign Funds. Issues stemming from rising election expenses were, for much of the past two decades, linked to substantial candidate reliance on PAC contributions. The perception that fundraising pressures might lead candidates to tailor their appeals to the most affluent and narrowly "interested" sectors raised perennial questions about the resulting quality of representation of the whole society. The role of PACs, in itself and relative to other sources, became a major issue; in retrospect, however, it appears that the issue was really about the role of interest groups and money in elections, PACs being the most visible vehicle thereof. As discussed below, the PAC issue per se has seemed greatly diminished by recent events, while concerns over interest group money through other channels have grown.

Through the 1980s, statistics showed a significant increase in PAC importance. From 1974-1988, PACs grew in numbers from 608 to a high of 4,268, in contributions to House and Senate candidates from $12.5 million to $147.8 million (a 400% rise in constant dollars), and in relation to other sources from 15.7% of congressional campaign receipts to 33.7%. While PACs remain a considerable force, data show a relative decline in their role since 1988: the percentage of PAC money in total receipts dropped to a low of 27% in 1994 (rising slightly through 1998, to 29.7%); PAC numbers dropped to 3,798 in 1998; contributions to candidates rose negligibly in constant dollars ($206.8 million in 1998); and, after individual giving had been declining as a component (vis-a-vis PACs), some leveling off has occurred, with individuals giving 62% of Senate and 53% of House receipts in 1998, for example.

Despite aggregate data on the relative decline of PACs, they still provide a considerable share in various subgroups. For example, in 1998, House candidates got 36% of their funds from PACs; House incumbents received 42%. To critics, PACs raise troubling issues in the campaign financing debate: Are policymakers beholden to special interests for election help, impairing their ability to make policy choices in the national interest? Do PACs overshadow average citizens, particularly in Members' states and districts? Does the appearance of quid pro quo relationships between special interest givers and politician recipients, whether or not they actually exist, seriously undermine public confidence in the political system?

PAC defenders view them as reflecting the nation's historic pluralism, representing not a monolithic force but a wide variety of interests. Rather than overshadowing individual citizens, these observers see them merely as groups of such citizens, giving voice to many who were previously uninvolved. PACs are seen as promoting, not hindering, electoral competition, by funding challengers in closely contested races. In terms of influencing legislative votes, donations are seen more as rewards for past votes than as inducements to alter future ones. Defenders also challenge the presumed dichotomy between special and national interest, viewing the latter as simply the sum total of the former. PACs, they argue, afford clearer knowledge of how interest groups promote their agendas, particularly noteworthy in light of the flood of unregulated and undisclosed money since 1996.

Competitiveness in Elections. Many view the campaign finance system in terms of a general imbalance in resources between incumbents and challengers, as evidenced by a spending ratio of more than 3.5:1 in recent House and some 2:1 in recent Senate elections. (In 1998, there was a much closer ratio in the House, with an average expenditure of $643,000 for an incumbent vs. $252,000 for a challenger--a 2.6 to 1 ratio, while the average Senate incumbent's $4.7 million exceeded the average challenger's $2.9 million by 1.6 to 1.) Incumbents' generally easier access to money is seen as the real problem, not the aggregate amounts spent by all candidates.

Those concerned about competitiveness also view the PAC issue through this lens. With some 79% of PAC funds going to incumbents in 1998, the question of PACs "buying access" with those most likely to be elected is seen as a more serious problem than the generally high amounts of aggregate PAC giving. But others dispute that the problem is really an incumbency one or that electoral competition should be the main goal of reform. After all, there is a fair degree of turnover in Congress (through defeats, retirements, etc.), and the system does allow changed financing patterns with sometimes unexpected results, as it did in 1994. Aggregate incumbent-challenger disparities may be less meaningful, it is noted, than those on the closer spending levels in hotly contested or open races.

Today's Paramount Issue: Perceived Loopholes in Current Law

Interest has intensified, especially since 1996, over campaign finance practices that some see as undermining the law's contribution and expenditure limits and its disclosure requirements. Although these practices may be legal, they are seen as "loopholes" through which electoral influence is sought by spending money in ways that detract from public confidence in the system and that are beyond the scope intended by Congress. Some of the prominent practices are bundling, soft money, independent expenditures, and issue advocacy.

Bundling. This involves collecting checks for (and made payable to) a specific candidate by an intermediate agent. A PAC or party may thus raise money far in excess of what it can legally contribute and receive recognition for its endeavors by the candidate.

Soft Money. This refers to money that may indirectly influence federal elections but is raised and spent outside the purview of federal laws and would be illegal if spent directly on a federal election. The significance of soft money stems from several factors: (1) many states permit direct union and corporate contributions and individual donations in excess of $25,000 in state campaigns, all of which are prohibited in federal races; (2) under the 1979 FECA Amendments and FEC rulings, such money may be spent by state and local parties in large or unlimited amounts on grassroots organizing and voter drives that may benefit all party candidates; and (3) publicly-funded presidential candidates may not spend privately raised money in the general election. In recent presidential elections, national parties have waged extensive efforts to raise money for their state affiliates, partly to boost the national tickets beyond what could be spent directly. Incomplete data for 2000 show that over $487 million in soft money was raised by the major parties, nearly double the $262 million raised in 1996.

Independent Expenditures. The 1976 Buckley ruling allowed unlimited spending by individuals or groups on communications with voters to expressly support or oppose clearly identified federal candidates, made without coordination or consultation with any candidate. Independent expenditures totaled $11.1 million in 1992 and $22.4 million in 1996. These expenditures may hinder a candidate's ability to compete with both an opponent and outside groups. They may also impair a sense of accountability between a candidate and voters, and many question whether some form of unprovable coordination may often occur in such cases.

Issue Advocacy. Although federal law regulates expenditures in connection with federal elections, it uses a fairly narrow definition for what constitutes such spending, per several court rulings on First Amendment grounds. The law, as affected by court rulings, allows regulation only of communications containing express advocacy, i.e., that use explicit terms urging the election or defeat of clearly identified federal candidates. By avoiding such terms, groups may promote their views and issue position in reference to particular elected officials, without triggering the disclosure and source restrictions of the FECA. Such activity, known as issue advocacy, is often perceived as having the intent of bolstering or detracting from the public image of officials who are also candidates for office. In 1996, an estimated $135 million was spent on issue advocacy; the estimate for 1998 ranged from $275-$340 million; and, as of September 1, the 2000 estimate had already reached $342 million, before the critical, final two months of the election. Also, groups ranging from labor unions to the Christian Coalition promote their policy views through voter guides, which present candidates' views on issues in a way that some see as helpful to some candidates and harmful to others, without meeting the standards for FECA coverage.

Policy Options

The policy debate over campaign finance laws proceeds from the philosophical differences over the underlying issues discussed above, as well as the more practical, logistical questions over the proposed solutions. Two primary considerations frame this debate. What changes can be made that will not raise First Amendment objections, given court rulings in Buckley and other cases? What changes will not result in new, unforeseen, and more troublesome practices? These considerations are underscored by the experience with prior amendments to FECA, such as PAC growth after the 1974 limits on contributions.

Just as the overriding issues centered until recently around election costs and funding sources, the most prominent legislation long focused on controlling campaign spending, usually through voluntary systems of public funding or cost-reduction benefits, and on altering the relative importance of various funding sources. Some saw both concepts primarily in the context of promoting electoral competition, to remedy or at least not exacerbate perceived inequities between incumbents and challengers. Increasingly since the mid-1980s, and particularly since the 1996 elections, concerns over perceived loopholes that undermine federal regulation have led to proposals to curb such practices. Conversely, some proposals have urged less regulation, on the ground that it inherently invites circumvention, while still other proposals have focused exclusively on improving or expanding disclosure.

Proposals on Longstanding Issues

Campaign Spending Limits and Government Incentives or Benefits. Until the late 1990s, the campaign reform debate often focused on the desirability of campaign spending limits. To a great extent, this debate was linked with public financing of elections. The coupling of these two controversial issues stemmed from Buckley's ban on mandatory spending limits, while allowing voluntary limits, with adherence a prerequisite for subsidies. Hence the notion arose in the 1970s that spending limits must be tied to public benefits, absent a constitutional amendment.

Public funding not only might serve as an inducement to voluntary limits, but by limiting the role of private money, it is billed as the strongest measure toward promoting the integrity of and confidence in the electoral process. Furthermore, it could promote competition in districts with strong incumbents or one-party domination. Public financing of congressional elections has been proposed in nearly every Congress since 1956 and has passed in several Congresses. The nation has had publicly funded presidential elections since 1976, and tax incentives for political donations were in place from 1972 to 1986.

Objections to public financing are numerous, many rooted in philosophical opposition to funding elections with taxpayer money, supporting candidates whose views are antithetical to those of many taxpayers, and adding another government program in the face of some cynicism toward government spending. The practical objections are also serious: How can a system be devised that accounts for different natures of districts and states, with different styles of campaigning and disparate media costs, and is fair to all candidates--incumbent, challenger, or open-seat, major or minor party, serious or "longshot?"

A major challenge to spending limit supporters has been how to curb, if not eliminate, public funding from their proposals. Although spending limits may have wide public support, most evidence suggests far less support for public financing. In the 105th Congress, the principal reform bills debated on the floor contained neither campaign spending limits nor public funding, reflecting not only the overriding concerns over soft money and issue advocacy but also the changed political climate since the 1970s.

Stemming from the spending limits debate have been proposals to lower campaign costs, without spending limits. Proposals for free or reduced rate broadcast time and postage have received some notable bipartisan support. Such ideas seek to reduce campaign costs and the need for money, without the possibly negative effects of arbitrary limits.

Changing the Balance Among Funding Sources. Until recently, most proposed bills sought, at least in part, to curb PACs' perceived influence, either directly, through a ban or reduced limits, or indirectly, through enhancing the role of individuals and parties. Current law allows individuals to give $1,000 per candidate, per election, while most PACs (if they are "multicandidate committees") may give $5,000 per candidate, increasing their ability to assist candidates, and without an aggregate limit such as that affecting individuals.

Three chief methods of direct PAC curbs were prominent in proposals advanced through the mid-1990s: banning PAC money in federal elections; lowering the $5,000 limit; and limiting candidates' aggregate PAC receipts. These concepts were included, for example, in all of the bills that the House and Senate voted on in the 101st-104th Congresses. Although support for such proposals was fueled by a desire to reduce the perceived role of interest groups, each proposal had drawbacks, such as constitutional questions about limiting speech and association rights and the more practical concern over devaluation of the $5,000 limit by inflation since it was set in 1974.

Yet another concern raised during that period was the potential encouragement for interest groups to shift resources to "independent" activities, which are less accountable to voters and more troublesome for candidates in framing the debate. Furthermore, independent advertisements were often marked by negativity and invective. If such prospects gave pause to lawmakers during the 1980s, the surge of financial activity outside the framework of federal election law since 1996 has largely dampened attempts to further limit PACs. The major reform bills in the 105th and 106th Congresses contained no further PAC restrictions.

Partly because of this problem, both before and after 1996, many have looked to more indirect ways to curb PACs and interest groups, such as raising limits on individual or party donations to candidates. These increases have also been proposed on a contingency basis to offset such other sources as wealthy candidates spending large personal sums on their campaigns. While higher limits might counterbalance PACs and other groups and offset effects of inflation, opponents observe that few Americans can afford to give even $1,000, raising age-old concerns about "fat cat" contributors.

House Republicans have pushed to boost the role of individuals in candidates' states or districts, to increase ties between Members and constituents. By requiring a majority of funds to come from the state or district (or prohibiting out-of-state funds), supporters expect to indirectly curb PACs, typically perceived as out-of-state, or Washington, influences.

Support also exists for increasing or removing party contribution and coordinated expenditure limits, based on the notions that the party role can be maximized without leading to influence peddling and on strengthening party ties to facilitate effective policymaking. Opponents note that many of the prominent allegations in 1996 involved party-raised funds. Also, even with some degree of philosophical agreement on increasing the party role, current political realities present some obstacles, i.e., the difference in the relative resources of the Republican national committees', whose federal accounts raised over $295 million in the 2000 election cycle, and the Democratic committees, which raised $173 million.

Promoting Electoral Competition. Proposals to reduce campaign costs without limits are linked to broader concerns about electoral competition. Political scientists tend to view spending limits as giving an advantage to incumbents, who begin with high name recognition and perquisites of office (e.g., staff, newsletters). Challengers often spend money just to build name recognition. Limits, unless high, may augment an institutional bias against challengers or unknown candidates. (Conversely, public funding could help challengers to compete with well-funded incumbents.)

Many of those concerned about electoral competition consequently have opposed spending limits, although they are philosophically opposed to public funding. These individuals tend to favor more "benign" forms of regulation, such as allowing higher limits on party contributions to challengers in early stages, or, generally, allowing greater latitude in challengers' ability to raise needed funds. At the very least, these individuals insist that changes not be made that, in their view, exacerbate perceived problems.

Proposals to Close Perceived Loopholes in Current Law

Proposals have increasingly addressed perceived loopholes in the FECA, and indeed this area is now the primary focus of reform efforts. This debate underscores a basic philosophical difference between those who favor and oppose government regulation of campaign finances. Opponents say that regulation invites attempts at subterfuge, that interested money will always find its way into elections, and that the most one can do is see that it is disclosed. Proponents argue that while it is hard to restrict money, it is a worthwhile goal, hence one ought to periodically fine-tune the law to correct "unforeseen consequences." Proposed "remedies" stem from the latter view, i.e., curtail the practices as they arise.

Bundling. Most proposals in this area, which is seen as less an issue now than in prior years, would count contributions raised by an intermediary toward both the donor's and intermediary's limit. Hence, an agent who had reached the limit could not raise additional funds for that candidate. Proposals differ as to specific agents who could continue this practice (e.g., whether to ban bundling by party committees or by all PACs).

Independent Expenditures. Short of a constitutional amendment to allow mandatory limits on campaign spending (as the Senate debated in 1988, 1995, 1997, and 2000), most proposals aim to promote accountability. They have sought to prevent indirect consultation with candidates and to ensure that the public knows these efforts are not sanctioned by candidates. Many bills have sought to tighten definitions of independent expenditure and consultation and to require more prominent disclaimers on ads. Many spending limits/ benefits bills have provided subsidies so those attacked in such ads may adequately respond.

Soft Money. This practice has provided the greatest opportunity to date for spending money beyond the extent allowed under federal law. FEC rules that took effect in 1991 require national parties to disclose non-federal accounts and allocate soft versus hard (i.e., federally permissible) money. Hence, we are more aware of soft money today and better able, at least theoretically, to keep it from financing federal races than we were previously.

Serious differences exist regarding soft money. Reformers want to curb what they view as an inherent circumvention of federal limits, while parties want to protect a source of funding that has bolstered their grassroots efforts. Proposed reforms have included specifying a "federal election period" in which soft money cannot be spent by state parties; prohibiting national party committees and federal candidates from raising or distributing soft money (the first two being prominent features of the recent McCain-Feingold and Shays-Meehan bills); prohibiting the use of any soft money in mixed (federal-state) activities; codifying the FEC's requirements for allocation of soft versus hard money among federal, state, and local candidates; requiring disclosure of or limitation on spending by tax-exempt groups; and curbing or requiring disclosure of labor and corporate soft money (including limits on unions' political use of worker dues). Beyond legislative solutions have been proposals for the FEC to restrain soft money through promulgating new regulations. These differences reflect the lack of consensus on both the nature of and the solutions to the soft money problem, as well as the respective strategic concerns of the two major parties.

Issue Advocacy. Addressing this practice, a form of soft money, involves broadening the definition of federal election-related spending. A 1995 FEC regulation offered such a definition, using a "reasonable person" standard, but this was struck down by a 1st Circuit federal court in 1996; this decision was later upheld by an appeals court but is at variance with an earlier 9th Circuit ruling. The FEC has been reluctant to enforce the regulation pending further judicial or legislative action. Some bills (such as the Shays-Meehan bill that passed the 105th and 106th Congresses) have sought to codify a definition of "express advocacy" that allows a communication to be considered as a whole, in context of such external events as timing, to determine if it is election-related. The recent McCain-Feingold bills, incorporating language initially proposed by Senators Snowe and Jeffords, narrowed the scope of the proposed definition of what would be considered federal election-related and focused primarily on disclosure on such activity. Finding a definition that can withstand judicial scrutiny may be the key to bringing some of what is labeled "issue advocacy" under the FECA's regulatory framework. This has emerged since 1996 as probably the thorniest aspect of the campaign finance debate.

Legislative Action in Congress

Congress' consideration of campaign finance reform has steadily increased since 1986, when the Senate passed the PAC-limiting Boren-Goldwater Amendment, marking the first campaign finance vote in either house since 1979 (no vote was taken on the underlying bill).

With Senate control shifting to Democrats in 1986, each of the next four Congresses saw intensified activity, based on Democratic-leadership bills with voluntary spending limits combined with inducements to participation, such as public subsidies or cost-reduction benefits. In the 100th Congress, Senate Democrats were blocked by a Republican filibuster. In the 101st - 103rd Congresses, the House and Senate each passed comprehensive bills based on spending limits and public benefits; the bills were not reconciled in the 101st or 103rd,, while a conference version achieved in the 102nd was vetoed by President Bush.

With Republicans assuming control in the 104th Congress, neither chamber passed a reform bill. A bipartisan bill based on previous Democratic-leadership bills was blocked by filibuster in the Senate, while both Republican- and Democratic-leadership bills--with starkly different approaches--failed to pass in the House. [For further discussion, see CRS Report 98-26 (pdf), Campaign Finance Reform Activity in the 100th - 104th Congresses.]

In the 105th Congress, reform supporters succeeded in passing the Shays-Meehan bill in the House (H.R. 2183, as amended). Senate sponsors of its companion McCain-Feingold measure (S. 25, as revised) failed on three occasions to break a filibuster in opposition, however, and no vote occurred on the bill. For further discussion 105th Congress activity, see Campaign Finance Reform Electronic Briefing Book. Previous Congresses. 105th Congress.http://www.congress.gov/brbk/html/ebcam4.html.

106th Congress

During the 106th Congress, 85 reform bills (24 Senate, 61 House) were introduced, notably including S. 26 (McCain-Feingold), as considered in the previous Congress; S. 1593, a more narrowly-focused version thereof; S. 2941 (Hagel-Kerrey), a bipartisan bill to limit soft money and raise hard money contribution limits; H.R. 417 (Shays-Meehan), a slightly revised version of the bill passed by the House in 1998; H.R. 1867 (Hutchinson), the "freshman" bill of the 105th Congress; H.R. 1922 (Doolittle), a deregulation alternative from the prior Congress favored by many Republicans; H.R. 2668 (Thomas), proposing noncontroversial changes in federal election law; and H.R. 4762 (Houghton), requiring disclosure of section 527 political organizations' activities.

House. 1st session. Speaker Hastert announced plans to consider the issue during the week of September 13. Supporters of H.R. 417 sought an earlier vote, through a discharge petition by Blue Dog and freshman Democrats, but were able to garner 202 signatures--16 short of the 218 necessary--prior to the August recess. The House Administration Committee held hearings--June 17 and 29 and July 13 and 22--and, on August 2, ordered four bills reported: one favorably--H.R. 2668 (Thomas); two without recommendation--H.R. 1867 (Hutchinson) and H.R. 1922 (Doolittle); and H.R. 417, unfavorably. On August 5, the Rules Committee agreed on a rule, allowing for consideration of Shays-Meehan (as base bill), 10 amendments, and three substitutes: texts of the other bills reported by House Administration.

The rule--H.Res. 283 (H.Rept. 106-311)--was passed by voice vote, when debate began September 14. The House passed H.R. 417 (252-177), with three perfecting amendments--two on foreign money in U.S. elections, one on reimbursement for political use of government vehicles. Six perfecting amendments were defeated, as were three substitutes (Doolittle, Hutchinson, and Thomas); one perfecting amendment was withdrawn.

On November 3, the House Education and the Workforce Committee reported H.R. 2434 (Goodling), the Worker Paycheck Fairness Act of 1999. This measure had been offered as an amendment to Shays-Meehan but was withdrawn prior to a vote on it.

2nd session. On April 5, 2000, the Ways and Means Committee defeated an amendment to the Taxpayer Bill of Rights (H.R. 4163), to require public disclosure to the IRS for 527 organizations. The amendment, offered by Rep. Doggett, was based on his H.R. 4168, the "Underground Campaign Disclosure Act of 2000." A similar proposal by Representative Moore-H.R. 3688, the "Campaign Integrity Act of 2000," requiring reporting to the FEC, is the subject of a discharge petition (H.Res. 508) to expedite House consideration. Attempts to offer the Doggett legislation failed in the House on May 25, when a motion to recommit the telephone excise tax repeal bill with instructions to add the proposal failed by a 208-214 vote, and on June 9, when, by 202-216, a Doggett motion to recommit the Death Tax Elimination Act with instructions to add his proposal failed. Efforts to broaden the scope of the 527 proposals have included a bill offered by Rep. Castle (H.R. 4621).

The Ways and Means Subcommittee on Oversight held hearings June 20. A bill to require disclosure on a broad range of tax-exempt groups-H.R. 4717-was offered by Subcommittee Chairman Amo Houghton on June 22. The bill was ordered reported that day by the Ways and Means Committee, as amended by a substitute offered by Chairman Bill Archer (H.Rept. 106-702). On June 27, the House passed H.R. 4762 (Houghton) to require disclosure by 527 political organizations (only); the vote was 385-39. (The bill is virtually identical to S. 2583, which passed the Senate June 8 as an amendment by Senators McCain, Feingold, and Lieberman.)

Senate. 1st session. The Rules and Administration Committee held a hearing March 24, 1999 on hard money contribution limits. Plans by reform supporters to force debate on some form of McCain-Feingold before the August recess were shelved after Majority Leader Lott pledged debate by mid-October. In a move to augment support, sponsors of McCain-Feingold on September 16 offered S. 1593, consisting of three sections of the more comprehensive S. 26: curbing party soft money, protecting rights of dissenting non-union members regarding political use of dues money, and raising some contribution limits. Debate on S. 1593 began on October 13. Two amendments were adopted on October 14:

Two additional amendments were offered October 15, along with cloture motions:

A motion to table the Reid amendment failed October 18 by 1-92. Cloture motions on the Reid and Daschle amendments failed October 19 by 53-47 and 52-48, respectively. On October 20, the Senate voted (53-47) to table a measure allowing reconsideration of campaign reform and (52-48) to move on to other legislation. Majority Leader Lott declared the issue dead for this year, but McCain-Feingold sponsors vowed to continue their efforts.

2nd session. On November 4, 1999, Senator Mitch McConnell and Majority Leader Lott announced that the Rules and Administration Committee would hold hearings in the spring of 2000 on campaign reform, following which they would mark up S. 1816 (Hagel-Kerrey), to limit soft money donations to national parties, increase limits on hard money contributions, and increase and expedite disclosure. Hearings were held from March 22 - May 17, 2000; a planned June 14 mark-up was cancelled. This bill was later re-introduced as S. 2941 and, on July 27, 2000, placed on the Senate calendar for possible action.

On March 28, the Senate voted to table (67-33) a proposed constitutional amendment to give Congress and the states the power to set reasonable limits on contributions and expenditures in support of or in opposition to candidates for nomination and election to federal and state or local office. The proposal, the text of S.J.Res. 6 (Hollings-Specter), took the form of Senate amendment 2890 (S.Amdt. 2890) (to S.J.Res. 14).

On another front, reform advocates sought to require disclosure by tax-exempt groups engaged in election-related activity but which did not disclose their activities under the federal election laws. Of particular interest were political organizations organized under section 527 of the Internal Revenue Code, whose express purpose was to influence elections. Initial focus was on two bills offered by Senator Lieberman: S. 2582, to require most 527 organizations to be political committees under the FECA, and S. 2583, to require increased reporting to the IRS and make the information publicly available. On June 8, an amendment to the FY2001 Defense Authorization Act by Senators McCain, Feingold, and Lieberman, based on S. 2583, was debated and passed by the Senate on a 57-42 vote. Senate leaders, who opposed the amendment's inclusion in the defense measure, pledged they would bring up a broader disclosure measure during the 2nd session. On June 15, Senator Smith (OR) offered a GOP leadership bill (S. 2742) to expand disclosure's scope to include 501c(5) and (6) organizations, as well as 527s. The issue appeared to be settled, however, on June 29, when the Senate (by 92-6) passed H.R. 4762, requiring disclosure by 527 groups (only); the bill, almost identical to the McCain-Feingold-Lieberman amendment, was approved by the House June 27 and signed by President Clinton July 1 as P.L. 106-230.

107th Congress

As of January 22, 11 campaign reform bills have been introduced in the 107th Congress (7 in the House and 4 in the Senate). Two of these are new versions of bills from the 106th Congress and are receiving particular attention: S. 27, the McCain-Feingold bill, and S. 22, the Hagel-Landrieu bill. Supporters of McCain-Feingold are seeking a debate and vote early in the first session and are envisioning that floor amendments will be allowed to be offered.


LEGISLATION

S. 22 (Hagel-Landrieu)

Open and Accountable Campaign Financing Act of 2002. Imposes annual limit on soft money donations to national party committees. Increases (hard money) limits on individual and PAC contributions. Requires broadcasters to make available information on election-related or public policy advertising. Increases and expedites disclosure under federal election law. Introduced Jan. 22, 2001; referred to Committee on Rules and Administration.

S. 27 (McCain-Feingold)

Bipartisan Campaign Reform Act of 2001. Bans soft money raising by national parties and federal candidates. Curbs state party soft money spending on "federal election activity." Defines electioneering communication as a broadcast ad referring to a clearly identified federal candidate within 60 days of a general election or 30 days of a primary, to an audience that includes voters in that election. Requires disclosure of electioneering communications above $10,000, with identification of donors of $500 or more. Bans funding of electioneering messages with union or for-profit corporation funds. Requires greater notice of non-union members' rights to rebates of dues payments used for political purposes. Raises limits on individual contributions to state parties and on aggregate annual federal contributions. Introduced Jan. 22, 2001; referred to Committee on Rules and Administration.


FOR ADDITIONAL READING

CRS Issue Briefs

CRS Issue Brief IB98025. Campaign Finance: Constitutional and Legal Issues of Soft Money, by L. Paige Whitaker.

CRS Reports

CRS Report 97-973 (pdf). Business and Labor Spending in U.S. Elections, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RS20346. Campaign Finance Bills in the 106th Congress: Comparison of Shays-Meehan, as passed, with McCain-Feingold, as revised, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RL30162 (pdf). Campaign Finance Bills in the 106th Congress: House, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RL30166 (pdf). Campaign Finance Bills in the 106th Congress: Senate, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RL30299. Campaign Finance Debate in the 106th Congress: Comparison of Measures Under House Consideration, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RS20073 (pdf). Campaign Finance Bills, 106th Congress: Comparison of Shays-Meehan & McCain-Feingold Proposals, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report 98-26 (pdf). Campaign Finance Reform Activity in the 100th - 104th Congresses, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report 98-282. Campaign Finance Reform: A Legal Analysis of Issue and Express Advocacy, by L. Paige Whitaker.

CRS Report RL30669 (pdf). Campaign Finance Regulation Under the First Amendment: Buckley v. Valeo and its Supreme Court Progeny, by L. Paige Whitaker and Christopher A. Jennings.

CRS Report 97-1040. Campaign Financing: Highlights and Chronology of Current Federal Law, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RL30582. 527 Organizations: How the Differences in Tax and Election Laws Permit Certain Organizations to Engage in Issue Advocacy without Public Disclosure and Proposals for Change, by Marie B. Morris.

CRS Report 97-680. Free and Reduced-Rate Television Time for Political Candidates, by Joseph E. Cantor, Denis Steven Rutkus, and Kevin B. Greely.

CRS Report 97-91 (pdf). Soft and Hard Money in Contemporary Elections: What Federal Law Does and Does Not Regulate, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report RS20133 (pdf). The Presidential Election Campaign Fund and Tax Checkoff: Background and Current Issues, by Joseph E. Cantor.

CRS Report 97-618. The Use of Labor Union Dues for Political Purposes: A Legal Analysis, by L. Paige Whitaker.

CRS Report 97-555 (pdf). The Use of Union Dues for Political Purposes: A Discussion of Agency Fee Objectors and Public Policy, by Gail McCallion.


Return to CONTENTS section of this Issue Brief.